A little over a
month ago, in early November, more than seventy students in Professor N. Gregory
Mankiw’s introductory economics course at Harvard University stood up
and walked out of the lecture. They organized this walk-out to protest
the course’s neoliberal predispositions, the corporatization of higher
education, and the growing burden of student debt. The students explained that
their action was in solidarity with Occupy
Wall Street, and went on to join a march in downtown Boston.
In organizing
this action, the students drew attention to a problem that has its roots
in the mainstream neoclassical theory that dominates today’s economics
departments. According to such theory, the discipline is a positive science that
can be used to reach empirical judgments free of bias and ideology. This way of
thinking about economics has generated elegant mathematical models, but these
cannot compensate for its incorrect assumptions. The Harvard student protest,
and the Occupy movement more broadly, prompt reconsideration of what it
might mean to walk out on mainstream economics.
The primary
problem with neoclassical economics is that its conceptual apparatus is supposed
to transcend social and class relations. In fact, however, this supposed
transcendence conceals capitalism’s natural
inequality. Focused only on the way economic relations look superficially
(i.e. like relations between things), neoclassical economics is not able
to analyze the exploitative and alienating relations that underlie the process
of exchange, relations that are becoming clearer and clearer to masses of
discontented and dispossessed workers as a result of the current crisis.
The fact that
the majority of academic economists rarely address these concerns is
certainly not a matter of intelligence, but rather one of ideology
and class allegiance. As Marx and Engels wrote in The German Ideology:
“The ideas of the ruling class are in every epoch the ruling ideas: i.e., the
class which is the ruling material force of society, is at the same
time its ruling intellectual force.” In his Prison Notebooks,
Antonio Gramsci developed this analysis further, drawing attention to the
role of intellectuals in capitalist society:“The intellectuals are the dominant
group’s deputies exercising the subaltern functions of social hegemony and
political government. These comprise… The ‘spontaneous’ consent given
by the great masses of the population to the general direction
imposed on social life by the dominant fundamental group.
”It is because of
the above reasons that orthodox economics is normative and apologetic. It is more
interested in defending the interests of the capitalist class and
its hangers-on (the 1%) than in critical inquiry. Neoclassical economics is, in
short, the economics of capital.
The urgent need now is for a political
economy of the working class, one which includes the ‘old’ proletariat of
the factories and the ‘new’ precariat of part-time work, exhausting ‘flexible’ hours,
intensive exploitation, and, in general, of precarious employment
circumstances. Such an economics would provide a theoretical foundation for the
liberation of humanity; that is,for a society where the free development of each individual
is a condition for the free development of all.
Although radical
political economists do integrate capitalist class relations into their
theories, for orthodox economists to join their heterodox colleagues would require
nothing less than a revolution in their
way of thinking. It would involve understanding capital not as a thing, but as
the independent social power of capitalists over workers, of the primacy of profits
over human needs and rights. Politically, it would entail abandoning the
principles of neoliberalism, resisting the commodification of the commons,
and fighting for an economy geared towards the satisfaction of human needs and
built upon the foundations of dignity, justice, equality, decentralized planning,
and workplace democracy. Economics is thus both a social science and
acontested battleground - one that the Occupy movement needs to fight for.
The most enduring critiques of established economic dogmas –Marxist
critiques, Keynesian, and others – were backed by popular movements that demand
edradical social and political change. People fought for new economies, and
social and political change, in their workplaces and in the streets. Today, after
years of political and ideologicalde feats at the hands of the 1%, we can and must
draw conclusions different from those of economic orthodoxy. It
is imperative to show that working people do not have to pay for
capital-ism’s crises through cuts to social services, unemployment, lower
living standards, poverty, and depression. Furthermore, as part of
this struggle, it is necessary to emphasize the unity of the 99%: those
engaging in both manual and intellectual labour, unionized and non-unionized,
legal and ‘illegal’ workers, regardless of skin color or sex.
In order to confront the prevailing economic thought,
however, it is necessary to make clear that economics is not pure mathematics
and economic thinking is not not only for technocrats. The disciplines of
political science, sociology, economics, history, and philosophy are
deeply interconnected. Their connection reflects of the real interactions
between the market economy, the state, the political sphere, social and class
relations, and ideology. To argue that economics is an objective science divorced
from these spheres is precisely to misunderstand it. It is to view capitalism’s
crises as natural disasters rather than as products of the system’s
contradictions.
Against
such a perspective, we must approach social science with the courage, as Marx
urged, to undertake “ruthless criticism of everything existing,” not afraid of
its own conclusions or conflicts with the
powers that be. To take a step in this direction means deciding between
real democracy and cannibalistic capitalism. It is to take sides on the
burning question that confronts humanity in our time: socialism or
barbarism.
Δεν υπάρχουν σχόλια:
Δημοσίευση σχολίου